|
The Social Ideology
of the Motorcar
André Gorz
The worst thing about cars is that they are like castles or villas by the sea: luxury
goods invented for the exclusive pleasure of a very rich minority, and which in conception
and nature were never intended for the people. Unlike the vacuum cleaner, the radio, or
the bicycle, which retain their use value when everyone has one, the car, like a villa by
the sea, is only desirable and useful insofar as the masses don't have one. That is how in
both conception and original purpose the car is a luxury good. And the essence of luxury
is that it cannot be democratised. If everyone can have luxury, no one gets any advantages
from it. On the contrary, everyone diddles, cheats, and frustrates everyone else, and is
diddled, cheated, and frustrated in return.
This is pretty much common knowledge in the case of the seaside villas. No politico has
yet dared to claim that to democratise the right to vacation would mean a villa with
private beach for every family. Everyone understands that if each of 13 or 14 million
families were to use only 10 meters of the coast, it would take 140,000km of beach in
order for all of them to have their share! To give everyone his or her share would be to
cut up the beaches in such little strips-or to squeeze the villas so tightly together-that
their use value would be nil and their advantage over a hotel complex would disappear. In
short, democratisation of access to the beaches point to only one solution-the
collectivist one. And this solution is necessarily at war with the luxury of the private
beach, which is a privilege that a small minority takes as their right at the expense of
all.
Now, why is it that what is perfectly obvious in the case of the beaches is not
generally acknowledged to be the case for transportation? Like the beach house, doesn't a
car occupy scarce space? Doesn't it deprive the others who use the roads (pedestrians,
cyclists, streetcar and bus drivers)? Doesn't it lose its use value when everyone uses his
or her own? And yet there are plenty of politicians who insist that every family has the
right to at least one car and that it's up to the "government" to make it
possible for everyone to park conveniently, drive easily in the city, and go on holiday at
the same time as everyone else, going 70 mph on the roads to vacation spots.
The monstrousness of this demagogic nonsense is immediately apparent, and yet even the
left doesn't disdain resorting to it. Why is the car treated like a sacred cow? Why,
unlike other "privative" goods, isn't it recognised as an antisocial luxury? The
answer should be sought in the following two aspects of driving:
- Mass motoring effects an absolute triumph of bourgeois ideology on the level of daily
life. It gives and supports in everyone the illusion that each individual can seek his or
her own benefit at the expense of everyone else. Take the cruel and aggressive selfishness
of the driver who at any moment is figuratively killing the "others," who appear
merely as physical obstacles to his or her own speed. This aggressive and competitive
selfishness marks the arrival of universally bourgeois behaviour, and has come into being
since driving has become commonplace. ("You'll never have socialism with that kind of
people," an East German friend told me, upset by the spectacle of Paris traffic).
- The automobile is the paradoxical example of a luxury object that has been devalued by
its own spread. But this practical devaluation has not yet been followed by an ideological
devaluation. The myth of the pleasure and benefit of the car persists, though if mass
transportation were widespread its superiority would be striking. The persistence of this
myth is easily explained. The spread of the private car has displaced mass transportation
and altered city planning and housing in such a way that it transfers to the car functions
which its own spread has made necessary. An ideological ("cultural") revolution
would be needed to break this circle. Obviously this is not to be expected from the ruling
class (either right or left).
Let us look more closely now at these two points.
When the car was invented, it was to provide a few of the very rich with a completely
unprecedented privilege: that of travelling much faster than everyone else. No one up to
then had ever dreamt of it. The speed of all coaches was essentially the same, whether you
were rich or poor. The carriages of the rich didn't go any faster than the carts of the
peasants, and trains carried everyone at the same speed (they didn't begin to have
different speeds until they began to compete with the automobile and the aeroplane). Thus,
until the turn of the century, the elite did not travel at a different speed from the
people. The motorcar was going to change all that. For the first time class differences
were to be extended to speed and to the means of transportation.
This means of transportation at first seemed unattainable to the masses - it was so
different from ordinary means. There was no comparison between the motorcar and the
others: the cart, the train, the bicycle, or the horse-car. Exceptional beings went out in
self-propelled vehicles that weighed at least a ton and whose extremely complicated
mechanical organs were as mysterious as they were hidden from view. For one important
aspect of the automobile myth is that for the first time people were riding in private
vehicles whose operating mechanisms were completely unknown to them and whose maintenance
and feeding they had to entrust to specialists. Here is the paradox of the automobile: it
appears to confer on its owners limitless freedom, allowing them to travel when and where
they choose at a speed equal to or greater than that of the train. But actually, this
seeming independence has for its underside a radical dependency. Unlike the horse rider,
the wagon driver, or the cyclist, the motorist was going to depend for the fuel supply, as
well as for the smallest kind of repair, on dealers and specialists in engines,
lubrication, and ignition, and on the interchangeability of parts. Unlike all previous
owners of a means of locomotion, the motorist's relationship to his or her vehicle was to
be that of user and consumer-and not owner and master. This vehicle, in other words, would
oblige the owner to consume and use a host of commercial services and industrial products
that could only be provided by some third party. The apparent independence of the
automobile owner was only concealing the actual radical dependency.
The oil magnates were the first to perceive the prize that could be extracted from the
wide distribution of the motorcar. If people could be induced to travel in cars, they
could be sold the fuel necessary to move them. For the first time in history, people would
become dependent for their locomotion on a commercial source of energy. There would be as
many customers for the oil industry as there were motorists-and since there would be as
many motorists as there were families, the entire population would become the oil
merchants' customers. The dream of every capitalist was about to come true. Everyone was
going to depend for their daily needs on a commodity that a single industry held as a
monopoly.
All that was left was to get the population to drive cars. Little persuasion would be
needed. It would be enough to get the price of a car down by using mass production and the
assembly line. People would fall all over themselves to buy it. They fell over themselves
all right, without noticing they were being led by the nose. What, in fact, did the
automobile industry offer them? Just this: "From now on, like the nobility and the
bourgeoisie, you too will have the privilege of driving faster than everybody else. In a
motorcar society the privilege of the elite is made available to you."
People rushed to buy cars until, as the working class began to buy them as well,
defrauded motorists realised they had been had. They had been promised a bourgeois
privilege, they had gone into debt to acquire it, and now they saw that everyone else
could also get one. What good is a privilege if everyone can have it? It's a fool's game.
Worse, it pits everyone against everyone else. General paralysis is brought on by a
general clash. For when everyone claims the right to drive at the privileged speed of the
bourgeoisie, everything comes to a halt, and the speed of city traffic plummets-in Boston
as in Paris, Rome, or London-to below that of the horsecar; at rush hours the average
speed on the open road falls below the speed of a bicyclist.
Nothing helps. All the solutions have been tried. They all end up making things worse.
No matter if they increase the number of city expressways, beltways, elevated crossways,
16- lane highways, and toll roads, the result is always the same. The more roads there are
in service, the more cars clog them, and city traffic becomes more paralysingly congested.
As long as there are cities, the problem will remain unsolved. No matter how wide and fast
a superhighway is, the speed at which vehicles can come off it to enter the city cannot be
greater than the average speed on the city streets. As long as the average speed in Paris
is 10 to 20 kmh, depending on the time of day, no one will be able to get off the beltways
and autoroutes around and into the capital at more than 10 to 20 kmh.
The same is true for all cities. It is impossible to drive at more than an average of
20 kmh in the tangled network of streets, avenues, and boulevards that characterise the
traditional cities. The introduction of faster vehicles inevitably disrupts city traffic,
causing bottlenecks-and finally complete paralysis.
If the car is to prevail, there's still one solution: get rid of the cities. That is,
string them out for hundreds of miles along enormous roads, making them into highway
suburbs. That's what's been done in the United States. Ivan Illich sums up the effect in
these startling figures: "The typical American devotes more than 1500 hours a year
(which is 30 hours a week, or 4 hours a day, including Sundays) to his [or her] car. This
includes the time spent behind the wheel, both in motion and stopped, the hours of work to
pay for it and to pay for gas, tires, tolls, insurance, tickets, and taxes .Thus it takes
this American 1500 hours to go 6000 miles (in the course of a year). Three and a half
miles take him (or her) one hour. In countries that do not have a transportation industry,
people travel at exactly this speed on foot, with the added advantage that they can go
wherever they want and aren't restricted to asphalt roads."
It is true, Illich points out, that in non-industrialised countries travel uses only 3
to 8% of people's free time (which comes to about two to six hours a week). Thus a person
on foot covers as many miles in an hour devoted to travel as a person in a car, but
devotes 5 to 10 times less time in travel. Moral: The more widespread fast vehicles are
within a society, the more time - beyond a certain point- people will spend and lose on
travel. It's a mathematical fact.
The reason? We've just seen it: The cities and towns have been broken up into endless
highway suburbs, for that was the only way to avoid traffic congestion in residential
centres. But the underside of this solution is obvious: ultimately people can't get around
conveniently because they are far away from everything. To make room for the cars,
distances have increased. People live far from their work, far from school, far from the
supermarket - which then requires a second car so the shopping can be done and the
children driven to school. Outings? Out of the question. Friends? There are the
neighbours.. .and that's it. In the final analysis, the car wastes more time than it saves
and creates more distance than it overcomes. Of course, you can get yourself to work doing
60 mph, but that's because you live 30 miles from your job and are willing to give half an
hour to the last 6 miles. To sum it all up: "A good part of each day's work goes to
pay for the travel necessary to get to work." (Ivan Illich).
Maybe you are saying, "But at least in this way you can escape the hell of the
city once the workday is over." There we are, now we know: "the city," the
great city which for generations was considered a marvel, the only place worth living, is
now considered to be a "hell." Everyone wants to escape from it, to live in the
country. Why this reversal? For only one reason. The car has made the big city
uninhabitable. It has made it stinking, noisy, suffocating, dusty, so congested that
nobody wants to go out in the evening anymore. Thus, since cars have killed the city, we
need faster cars to escape on superhighways to suburbs that are even farther away. What an
impeccable circular argument: give us more cars so that we can escape the destruction
caused by cars.
From being a luxury item and a sign of privilege, the car has thus become a vital
necessity. You have to have one so as to escape from the urban hell of the cars.
Capitalist industry has thus won the game: the superfluous has become necessary. There's
no longer any need to persuade people that they want a car; it's necessity is a fact of
life. It is true that one may have one's doubts when watching the motorised escape along
the exodus roads. Between 8 and 9:30 a.m., between 5:30 and 7 p.m., and on weekends for
five and six hours the escape routes stretch out into bumper-to-bumper processions going
(at best) the speed of a bicyclist and in a dense cloud of gasoline fumes. What remains of
the car's advantages? What is left when, inevitably, the top speed on the roads is limited
to exactly the speed of the slowest car?
Fair enough. After killing the city, the car is killing the car. Having promised
everyone they would be able to go faster, the automobile industry ends up with the
unrelentingly predictable result that everyone has to go as slowly as the very slowest, at
a speed determined by the simple laws of fluid dynamics. Worse: having been invented to
allow its owner to go where he or she wishes, at the time and speed he or she wishes, the
car becomes, of all vehicles, the most slavish, risky, undependable and uncomfortable.
Even if you leave yourself an extravagant amount of time, you never know when the
bottlenecks will let you get there. You are bound to the road as inexorably as the train
to its rails. No more than the railway traveller can you stop on impulse, and like the
train you must go at a speed decided by someone else. Summing up, the car has none of the
advantages of the train and all of its disadvantages, plus some of its own: vibration,
cramped space, the danger of accidents, the effort necessary to drive it.
And yet, you may say, people don't take the train. Of course! How could they? Have you
ever tried to go from Boston to New York by train? Or from Ivry to Treport? Or from
Garches to Fountainebleau? Or Colombes to l'Isle-Adam? Have you tried on a summer Saturday
or Sunday? Well, then, try it and good luck to you! You'll observe that automobile
capitalism has thought of everything. Just when the car is killing the car, it arranges
for the alternatives to disappear, thus making the car compulsory. So first the capitalist
state allowed the rail connections between the cities and the surrounding countryside to
fall to pieces, and then it did away with them. The only ones that have been spared are
the high-speed intercity connections that compete with the airlines for a bourgeois
clientele. There's progress for you!
The truth is, no one really has any choice. You aren't free to have a car or not
because the suburban world is designed to be a function of the car-and, more and more, so
is the city world. That is why the ideal revolutionary solution, which is to do away with
the car in favour of the bicycle, the streetcar, the bus, and the driverless taxi, is not
even applicable any longer in the big commuter cities like Los Angeles, Detroit, Houston,
Trappes, or even Brussels, which are built by and for the automobile. These splintered
cities are strung out along empty streets lined with identical developments; and their
urban landscape (a desert) says, "These streets are made for driving as quickly as
possible from work to home and vice versa. You go through here, you don't live here. At
the end of the workday everyone ought to stay at home, and anyone found on the street
after nightfall should be considered suspect of plotting evil." In some American
cities the act of strolling in the streets at night is grounds for suspicion of a crime.
So, the jig is up? No, but the alternative to the car will have to be comprehensive.
For in order for people to be able to give up their cars, it won't be enough to offer them
more comfortable mass transportation. They will have to be able to do without
transportation altogether because they'll feel at home in their neighbourhoods, their
community. their human-sized cities, and they will take pleasure in walking from work to
home-on foot, or if need be by bicycle. No means of fast transportation and escape will
ever compensate for the vexation of living in an uninhabitable city in which no one feels
at home or the irritation of only going into the city to work or, on the other hand, to be
alone and sleep.
"People," writes Illich, "will break the chains of overpowering
transportation when they come once again to love as their own territory their own
particular beat, and to dread getting too far away from it." But in order to love
"one's territory" it must first of all be made liveable, and not trafficable.
The neighbourhood or community must once again become a microcosm shaped by and for all
human activities, where people can work, live, relax, learn, communicate, and knock about,
and which they manage together as the place of their life in common. When someone asked
him how people would spend their time after the revolution, when capitalist wastefulness
had been done away with, Marcuse answered, "We will tear down the big cities and
build new ones. That will keep us busy for a while."
These new cities might be federations of communities (or neighbourhoods) surrounded by
green belts whose citizens-and especially the schoolchildren-will spend several hours a
week growing the fresh produce they need. To get around everyday they would be able to use
all kinds of transportation adapted to a medium-sized town: municipal bicycles, trolleys
or trolley-buses, electric taxis without drivers. For longer trips into the country, as
well as for guests, a pool of communal automobiles would be available in neighbourhood
garages. The car would no longer be a necessity. Everything will have changed: the world,
life, people. And this will not have come about all by itself.
Meanwhile, what is to be done to get there? Above all, never make transportation an
issue by itself. Always connect it to the problem of the city, of the social division of
labour, and to the way this compartmentalises the many dimensions of life. One place for
work, another for "living," a third for shopping, a fourth for learning, a fifth
for entertainment. The way our space is arranged carries on the disintegration of people
that begins with the division of labour in the factory. It cuts a person into slices, it
cuts our time, our life, into separate slices so that in each one you are a passive
consumer at the mercy of the merchants, so that it never occurs to you that work, culture,
communication, pleasure, satisfaction of needs, and personal life can and should be one
and the same thing: a unified life, sustained by the social fabric of the community.
Le Sauvage September-October 1973
|